Protectionism

Becoming the victim of one’s own policies

Originally appeared on The Morning.

By Dhananath Fernando

At a recent press conference, the Central Bank of Sri Lanka (CBSL) announced that importing goods through open accounts was going to be banned as a move to curb the money transfer through undiyal and hawala. In my view, this will have a negative impact on the supply of essential food items, drugs, and some raw materials. 

When a merchant imports goods, they can pay their supplier through a letter of credit. A letter of credit is simply a letter of guarantee by a bank or a financial institution to the supplier/seller that the correct amount will be paid in full on time. To open a letter of credit, the Sri Lankan importers should be able to buy foreign exchange or simply purchase US Dollars. But as we are all aware, all Sri Lankan banks have a drastic shortage of foreign exchange. The shortage is of such severity that we can’t import essentials, and in some cases even life saving drugs. 

In the case of imports, if the buyer and the seller have mutual trust, a letter of credit is not mandatory. They can settle on a credit basis later on. The goods will be cleared on Documents against Payments (DP) or Documents against Acceptance (DA). Most importers and their buyers/suppliers have long-standing business relationships. They pay later either through different modes including hawala and undiyal. This is no secret. They pay an additional charge for hawala and undiyal to buy USD for a reason, which is simply that our banks don’t have sufficient dollars to facilitate imports even if the importer requests the opening of a letter of credit. Otherwise, no businessman would want to pay a higher price for forex if there were cheaper options available. Especially in the areas of food, medicine, essentials, and raw materials, these open account transactions are common. According to a recent news report, approximately $ 1.6-1.8 billion worth of transactions are done on open accounts every month. 

So what could happen when the Central Bank forces these importers to conduct transactions only through letters of credit? Simply put, they may not have any option other than to stop importing. Because banks don’t have USD, they can’t even import on open accounts to settle later. The Central Bank expects more USD to flow into formal channels since the demand for USD through undiyal and hawala is set to decline with the new regulation banning open accounts. Even if the Central Bank’s assumption is right, it won’t happen overnight. Given the uncertainty, importers will either hold or slow down the imports to observe the situation. It will take a few months to settle even if all USD inflows started flowing through official channels. What would happen to our essential food items, certain raw materials for businesses, and drugs during those long months? 

However, so far the Gazette notification has not been issued by the Central Bank, and we have to wait and observe the situation in the next few months.

It is not the first time the Central Bank has burnt its fingers by unnecessary attempts to control the market. 

First, the Central Bank imposed a 100% cash margin requirement on vehicle imports in 2018 and later vehicle importation was banned completely (1).

Later, the Central Bank’s 100% cash margin requirement on selected imports categorised as non-essentials was extended from vehicles to many other imports (2). This column questioned how an officer decides what is essential and what is not essential. A digital camera may not be considered an essential by a writer or a banker, but a camera is an essential to a wedding photographer whose livelihood depends on it. 

Then, the Central Bank stopped the forward purchasing market and only provided space to open letters of credit with a 180-day limit. 

It was then decided to artificially keep the currency at Rs. 200 per USD, and the undiyal and hawala market expanded dramatically.

All the main Key Performance Indicators (KPI) of the Central Bank have been eroded drastically during the same period in which these controls were imposed. Our inflation has increased to 29.8% and our food inflation has increased to almost 50%. Our currency has depreciated by more than 75% in a matter of a few months. Simply put, our Central Bank has fallen far short on all its key indicators regardless of back-to-back controls and interventions. Many new theories employed by CBSL economists, including Modern Monetary Theory, have backfired spectacularly and unfortunately it is the poor people who have to pay the ultimate price in hunger and inconvenience for the grave mistakes of the Central Bank and the Monetary Board.  

As a remedial action to these mistakes, our Central Bank has now made an attempt to ban open accounts and cripple the undiyal and hawala systems. 

In my humble opinion, this may potentially create shortages of essentials and inconvenience the traders and importers who have been supplying the essentials at a higher price. These merchants have been bearing the higher cost of the informal markets boosted by the Central Bank due to mistakes beyond their control made by policymakers. 

We have to first ask ourselves why an importer should bear a higher price on USD to import. Without fixing our monetary policy, there is no point passing the blame to the hawala and undiyal markets. They have existed for centuries in Sri Lanka and around the world because of their competitive and evolving nature. The buck stops with policymakers, and not with merchants or foriegn currency middlemen.

Quite frankly, it will accomplish very little to close the stable door after the horse has already bolted.  

References:

The opinions expressed are the author’s own views. They may not necessarily reflect the views of the Advocata Institute or anyone affiliated with the institute.

Walking the talk on reforms: First step to Lankan recovery

Originally appeared on The Morning.

By Dhananath Fernando

Often we all see the world the way we want to see it, and not as it is. Sri Lanka’s economic crisis is also seen by many people through their own perception of reality. 

In previous years, we believed that self-sufficiency, State-led industrialisation, State-centred economic planning, and more recently, Modern Monetary Theory, were the way forward for our economy. The current crisis has shown that none of that has really helped us; by contrast, it has exacerbated a poor situation to where we are today.  

Next comes the question of overcoming the crisis. This has to be analysed with context; the most significant piece of context is that we are facing the worst situation we’ve been in since independence in 1948 – and it is only getting worse. 

There are some suggestions to increase industrialisation, improve exports and the trade balance, and incentivise Foriegn Direct Investments (FDIs). However, it is of no use to have lofty goals of industrialisation when we can hardly provide an uninterrupted electricity supply. 

Foreign investors are planning to leave. Investors are by no means considering entering the country. Thus, potential solutions have to be evaluated based on this context. Simply having a wishlist of suggestions with minimal viability will add very little value at this juncture. We need rational solutions to solve the crisis immediately, rather than policies that can only be enacted in times of relative normalcy. 

The Government needs to bring its finances into a sustainable state. Revenue must increase and expenditure should be reduced. Reducing the losses of State enterprises is a way to reduce the deficit without touching social expenditure.

With that in mind, here are a few suggestions for reform:

1. Privatise SriLankan Airlines

At a time when people are struggling to feed their families and when our official usable reserves are less than $ 200 million, there are very few upsides to running a fully State-owned airline making losses equivalent to the value of our entire Samurdhi scheme, which, despite its flaws, is the main social safety net in Sri Lanka. Privatisation will provide strong signals that we are serious about reforms. 

For the last 15 years, we have not made any profits on SriLankan Airlines. We can disclose all finances and ask for interested companies to buy it outright with assets and liabilities. Having a higher liability than assets is the main problem in this instance. With the suspension of debt repayment of State enterprises, Treasury guarantees for the State are on hold at the moment. 

Even if we need to pay a certain amount to the buyer to take it off our hands and sell it off with staff, it is much better than keeping the enterprise in-house and incurring colossal losses repeatedly. The new buyer can be given the responsibility of staff restructuring. We can follow the playbook through which Air India was sold outright by the Modi Government. Our airline is unfortunately no longer an asset but a liability to our national coffers. 

However, it is not only the National Airline that makes losses. There are many institutes that add little value to the public, make massive losses, and are a very high burden on the Treasury. Some of these public enterprises are classified as ‘strategic’ and others as ‘non-strategic,’ but two things they have in common is that, more often than not, they make substantial losses and have very limited transparency. 

There were some discussions to revive Sri Lankan Airlines by appointing business leaders with a profit motive, converting it to a budget airline, and appointing committees to reform and restructure. We have run out of time to even attempt these options. Unfortunately, hard times require hard decisions and we do not have the time, money, or options to avoid them. 

With interest rates and Treasury bill interest rates reaching above 20%, running loss-making enterprises on borrowed money will make our local debt increasingly unstable the more we delay reforms. Most importantly, we don’t need to wait for pressure from creditors or the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to kickstart reforms; we can begin them now.

2. Better utilisation of idle assets

Improving service efficiency and increasing revenue of railways through Public-Private Partnerships (PPP) have to be the way forward for better utilisation of idle assets. 

Sri Lanka Railways is categorised as a department of the Government, even though it is actually a State-Owned Enterprise. Sri Lanka Railways holds a considerable amount of State land which is used very unproductively. 

Fort Railway Station, Maradana Railway Station, and the surrounding land along the track between these two stations are prime examples. Major railway stations such as Kollupitiya, Wellawatte, and Bambalapitiya are all prime beachfront properties which are very poorly maintained and completely underutilised. Land prices in Colombo are extremely high. There are plenty of such examples under the Railways Department with zero or negative value addition to our economy. Sri Lanka Railways first has to be made a State-Owned Enterprise, and then the sector needs to be opened for private sector investment. 

In the past, some train compartments were operated by private players and it was a very successful and lucrative business model. If we eliminate the State railway monopoly and open up the time table, tracks, and properties to the private sector, we can cut down on our fuel consumption significantly, provide a convenient service to passengers, and even turn a loss-making liability into a revenue-generating asset.

Given the very high energy prices at present – which are only set to increase – many people need the option of efficient and robust public transit infrastructure. In any case, the majority of people in Sri Lanka cannot afford to purchase and operate personal vehicles, and trains have been the main source of transportation in areas where they are available.

It is also of paramount importance that the most vulnerable segments of the population benefit from a rehauled cash transfer system, which should cover the energy price component in public transport. Everyone, regardless of their socio-economic stratification, should be given a fair chance to compete in life. 

However, it should be emphasised that these two steps alone will not help overcome the crisis. However, it is a good start to get the wheels rolling on reforms. These reforms will provide an unambiguous signal to investors and the world that we are no longer a NATO (No Action, Talk Only) nation, but a nation that walks the talk.

The opinions expressed are the author’s own views. They may not necessarily reflect the views of the Advocata Institute or anyone affiliated with the institute.

How protectionism killed Sri Lankan industry

Originally appeared on The Morning.

By Dhananath Fernando

Sri Lanka’s economic crisis was probably a crisis which was analysed (indeed over-analysed) and predicted from an early stage, but we failed to avoid it. We all knew that it was coming and therefore remedies were presented much earlier, but our policymakers simply turned a blind eye. They didn’t have the courage to face reality. Instead, they thought that wishful thinking would save Sri Lanka from the current crisis, and today, we have hit rock bottom. Unfortunately, we are just at the beginning of the crisis and have not even reached the recovery phase.  

It is important to reiterate that self-sufficiency, Modern Monetary Theory, industrial policy, protectionism, and import substitution failed yet again, and this time brought our people down on their knees. While we look towards solutions, we must also understand that it is not easy to rebuild an economy once it collapses. Recovery takes time, and recovery can only happen with the right set of policies.

There is one school of thought that argues that the lack of industrialisation is the reason for Sri Lanka’s balance of payments crisis. The main argument is that if we produced more to export, we would have had more USD revenue and this crisis would not have taken place. So the argument again comes back to import substitution, which involves banning imports or imposing higher tariffs on imports in order to produce locally. The argument is that this can save import expenditure while local manufacturing can scale up in order to focus on exports and bring export revenue. In the same theory, it is recommended that the government picks up which industries should be supported and which industries should not. This is simply going back to the same theory of the central planning model where a few officers decide which industries are good and which are bad. Often quoted examples for this are Japan, South Korea, and Vietnam. So today, let’s evaluate the strategy of industrialisation based on market principles. 

In simple terms, you become a good sailor by facing rough waters. Similarly the government selecting which industries to support and which industries to avoid will have consequences for all industries. Industrialisation should take place in a market system that optimally allocates all the available resources. If the government intervenes to assist one industry, it will have a knock-on effect on all other industries. Japan is indeed a classic example. The high-powered Japanese Ministry of Trade and Industry (MITI) recommended that Toyoda not produce cars. But he ignored their advice and today no explanations are required on Toyota’s success and competitiveness. In fact, in our apparel industry, big companies follow Toyoda’s example in the lean manufacturing techniques they pioneered. Rather than providing government support, price controls imposed by the Japanese Government impacted the automobile industry. So government intervention in the markets and industries is a sure recipe for failure. 

In Sri Lanka’s case, industries such as wall tiles, floor tiles, steel, aluminium, bathware, shoes, confectionery, and many others have been protected for decades. Have they become globally competitive due to protectionism and import substitution? In fact, import substitution is the worst we can do to develop exports because it creates an incentive to only produce for the local markets and discourages producers from producing for the global market given the tariff and non-tariff protection. Do our rubber, seafood, apparel, and electronic chips industries require any protection for them to be globally competitive? The simple answer is: no.  

In cricket terms, we can’t create a world class batsman by asking the bowlers to bowl loose deliveries. We can’t create a good bowler by asking the batsman to go soft on bowlers. Only in a competitive environment are heroes created. The protection is a sure way of killing the heroes and robbing poor consumers and exporters simultaneously. That is exactly what we have been doing for the last few decades. 

No export promotion can be done through import substitution; in fact, import substitution is killing our export potential. When the exporters have to pay more than 40% higher for construction materials, it is impossible for even our best performing exports to be competitive in global markets. 

If we observe the trade data, it is clear that our imports and exports are both declining as a percentage of GDP. In 2009, Sri Lanka had nine import taxes in addition to standard customs duties, and five of them are ‘para-tariffs’. Between 2004-2009, our total nominal protection doubled from 13.4% to 27.9%. Higher protectionism also indicates our continuous drop in both imports and exports.

Things got worse over time. The average effective rate of protection for manufacturing production increased from 47% to 63% from 2000 to 2015, and production for the domestic market was over 70% more profitable compared to production for exporting (World Bank, 2005; DCS, 2018). 

Accordingly, industrial policy and import substitution are contributory factors to where we are today with low exports and low productivity in the economy. 

In the history of industrialisation there are certain instances where some countries protected local industries, but in the success stories, protection had been given for a specified, strict time period or output and had a price-based structure.

Countries such as South Korea and Vietnam too became competitive not through import substitution but by allowing the markets to work. In a paper authored by Advocata Advisor Prof. Premachandra Athukorala, he quotes General Park Chung-Hee, who is considered the father of the Korean economic miracle: 

“The economic planning or long-range development programme must not be allowed to stifle creativity or spontaneity of private enterprises. We should utilise to the maximum extent the merit usually introduced by the price mechanism of free competition, thus avoiding the possible damages accompanying a monopoly system. There can be and will be no economic planning for the sake of planning itself.”

The opinions expressed are the author’s own views. They may not necessarily reflect the views of the Advocata Institute or anyone affiliated with the institute.

Trade, deglobalization and the new mercantilism

Originally appeared on the Hinrich Foundation

By Prof. Razeen Sally

The COVID-19 pandemic is accelerating shifts underway since the last global financial crisis (GFC). It ushers in a new era of deglobalisation and protectionism, indeed a new mercantilist world order.

Three global shifts will shape international trade. They will probably last beyond the immediate crisis to the “post-vaccine” future. The first is an accelerated shift from Market to State: more government interventions will further restrict markets. The second is to national unilateralism – governments acting on their own, often against each other – at the expense of global cooperation. The third is to more contested and unstable geopolitics, centred on US-China rivalry. Taken together, they herald a new mercantilism, whose main precedents are Europe and its colonial expansion in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, and the period between the two world wars in the first half of the twentieth century.

Mercantilism – the exercise of state power to control markets domestically and internationally – existed after 1945, but was constrained by the expansion of markets: it was relatively benign. But malign mercantilism governed the preceding decades, shattering domestic economies, shrinking individual freedom, destroying the world economy, and so poisoning international politics as to culminate in global war. Today’s emerging mercantilism is still far from that reality, but it risks heading in that direction.

Another set of historical precedents is also relevant. Increasingly, the US-China conflict today echoes that of the US and the Soviet Union in the “old” cold war. But China today, unlike the former Soviet Union, is an authoritarian (not totalitarian) power with a state-directed and partly globalised market economy (not a sealed-off command economy). China better resembles Germany and Japan as rising powers in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. And US-China rivalry today better resembles that of the UK and Germany before the first world war: a contest between the established power, with a liberal-democratic political system and a free-market economy, and a rising power, with an authoritarian political system and a state-guided market economy.

Three eras of international trade preceded the present pandemic. The first – the quarter-century until the GFC – was an era of unprecedented liberalisation and globalisation. The second – the near-decade after the GFC – saw globalisation stall, though not reverse, and trade growth stagnate alongside “creeping” protectionism. The third, starting in early 2017, was triggered by President Trump, partly to retaliate against increasing Chinese protectionism. It centred on a US-China trade war but rippled out into copycatting protectionism by other countries. Protectionism went from creeping to galloping.

This pandemic has triggered the worst deglobalisation since 1945. International trade may shrink by up to a third, foreign direct investment by up to 40 per cent, and international remittances by 20 per cent, this year. The trade outlook is worse than it was during the GFC in two ways. Now economic contraction is synchronised around the world; during and after the GFC, fast growth in emerging markets, led by China, cushioned the fall in trade and enabled a recovery. Now services trade is suffering even more than goods trade; travel and tourism have collapsed. The GFC, in contrast, hit goods trade hard but services trade was more resilient, especially fast-growing travel and tourism. Now there are signs of a protectionist upsurge, starting with export bans on medical equipment, with new restrictions on foreign ownership in the pipeline.

What is the medium-term – post-vaccine – trade outlook?

First, protectionism is likely to increase as a spillover of domestic state – particularly industrial-policy – interventions that last beyond the present crisis. Crisis-induced subsidies will be difficult to reverse wholesale and will have trade-discriminating effects. New screening requirements might have a chilling effect on foreign investment. These and other interventions to protect domestic sectors and national champions have a home-production bias. The list of “strategic” sectors to protect on “national security” grounds against foreign competition will likely expand. There will probably be more restrictions on migration and the cross-border movement of workers.

Two precedents are relevant: the “new protectionism” of the 1970s and ‘80s, which partly resulted from bigger, more interventionist government in domestic markets; and, more perniciously, the expansion of government after the first world war, which empowered interest groups to lobby effectively for restricted imports, foreign investment and immigration.

Second, national unilateralism – this time “illiberal unilateralism” – will likely expand and make effective regional and global policy cooperation more difficult. It bodes ill for the WTO, APEC and the G20, also for regional organisations such as ASEAN, and will cramp the liberalising effects of stronger preferential trade agreements. This only increases the prospect of tit-for-tat retaliation, starting with the Big Three (the US, EU and China), and copycatting protectionism that will spread around the world.

Third, the reorientation of global value chains will accelerate. Western multinationals will relocate parts of their production from China to other countries on cost grounds, as they have been doing, but increasingly on political-risk and security grounds as well. There will be a combination of onshoring, near-shoring and regionalisation of value chains, which will vary widely by sector. But the overall effect will be to raise costs for producers and consumers.

Fourth, international trade will be hit harder by a more fractured and conflictual geopolitical environment, especially US-China rivalry, but not helped either by an inward-looking and divided EU. It will be squeezed between more unstable geopolitics and the recalibration of states and markets – more “state” and less “market” – domestically.

All the above points to a new mercantilist trade order that might be more malign than benign, echoing the “new protectionism” of the 1970s and early ‘80s, or, even more worryingly, the 1920s and ‘30s.

My ideal world is a classical-liberal one: limited government, free markets and free trade, underpinned by appropriate domestic and international rules. I would add political liberalism and legally protected individual freedoms. The post-1945 global order was some distance from this classical-liberal ideal, but it was liberal enough to deliver unprecedented freedom and prosperity. From this vantage point, the new mercantilist order, with emerging malign characteristics, is alarming – bad economics, politics and international relations; bad for individual freedoms and global prosperity. As a realist, however, I must take the world “as it is” rather than indulge in wishful thinking. To improve the world, principled liberalism must be combined with practical realism.

I believe the two biggest threats to global order are rising illiberal populism in the West, endangering the West’s adherence to its own liberal values, and the increasingly aggressive illiberalism of the Chinese party-state. Both have mercantilist features that spill over the border into protectionism and restricted globalisation. Both feed off each other in a global negative-sum game. Hence both must be resisted: naivety and complacency should apply to neither.

China under Xi Jinping, with its mix of authoritarianism, a state-directed market economy and external assertiveness, is becoming a classic mercantilist power, like Germany and Japan in the late nineteenth century and early twentieth century. Its external power projection, especially in the last decade, looks quite different to that of the US in the Pax Americana. Of course, at times, here and there, the US threw its weight about unilaterally and arbitrarily. But the essence of US leadership was to provide public goods for a stable, open and prosperous world order. It did so by organising concerts of international and regional cooperation. In international trade, that took the form of the GATT, later the WTO, and the multilateral rules it administers.

China, in contrast, prioritises a combination of unilateral and bilateral action to expand and entrench its power. That subsumes the expansion of the PLA Navy in the East China Sea, South China Sea and Indian Ocean; and tight, asymmetric bilateral relations with smaller, weaker states in a twenty-first-century recreation of the ancient tributary system. The Belt and Road Initiative should be seen in this frame: a network of hub-and-spoke bilateral relationships in which China wields power over-dependent states. This is classic mercantilism. It privileges discretionary power, exercised unilaterally and bilaterally, over plurilateral and multilateral rules that constrain such power.

China – meaning the Chinese Communist party-state – presents a pressing challenge to the liberal world order. Dealing with this challenge will require some trade, technological and investment restrictions, and limited supply-chain decoupling. But that could easily descend into an all-round mercantilist and deglobalisation spiral. Hence China must be engaged at the same time, not least to preserve existing links that are mutually beneficial. Engagement and strategic decoupling need not be mutually exclusive. Still, this will prove an incredibly difficult, perhaps elusive, balancing act.

Liberal or semi-liberal small states and middle powers in Asia, the West and elsewhere have a crucial role to combat malign mercantilism. In Asia, this group includes Japan, South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Australia and New Zealand. They need to keep their economies and societies open; demonstrate best policy and institutional practice (as they have done in this pandemic crisis); build coalitions of the willing on trade and other issues; strengthen alliances with the US and EU to nudge them to be more outward-looking and globally constructive, and finesse a mix of strategic decoupling and engagement on China. But doing all that in a global mercantilist environment will be an uphill struggle.

Prof. Razeen Sally is a visiting associate professor at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy at the National University of Singapore. He is also the author of "Return to Sri Lanka: Travels in a Paradoxical Island."

Sri Lanka's Rajapaksa restoration is complete. What comes next?

Originally appeared on Nikkei Asia

By Prof. Razeen Sally

Government may have to rely on new Chinese loans to avert a macroeconomic crisis

Sri Lanka's parliamentary election on August 5 delivered a thumping victory for President Gotabaya Rajapaksa and his older brother Prime Minister Mahinda Rajapaksa's Sri Lanka Podujana Peramuna, or SLPP, party. Following Gotabaya Rajapaksa's decisive victory in the presidential election last November, what does the Rajapaksa family's unlimited rule portend for Sri Lanka and its external relations?

Illiberal democracy, a state-led economy, Sinhala-Buddhist supremacy -- Sinhala Buddhists are about 70% of the population, and a China-centric foreign policy were the hallmarks of Mahinda Rajapaksa's rule when he served as president until 2015. His surprise election defeat opened a window for liberal democracy, a more internationally open, private sector-led economy, reconciliation with ethno-religious minorities, and a more balanced foreign policy to reengage with the West and India.

But the coalition government that followed was a total disaster, crippled by no reform strategy, venomous internal warfare, corruption scandals and rank incompetence. The Rajapaksa restoration last November revived the core features of the previous Rajapaksa rule. But now Gotabaya Rajapaksa is in the driving seat, and Sri Lanka faces a COVID-19 plagued world.

With a handful of allies, the SLPP will have a two-thirds parliamentary majority, which will allow it to change the constitution at will. First will come the repeal of the Nineteenth Amendment, which limits presidential powers and strengthens parliament and the judiciary.

Optimists argue that Sri Lanka now has the political stability and decisive governance it lacked under the previous government. President Rajapaksa has centralized power in his small circle, crowded with retired senior military officers. Even more than his brother Mahinda, he favours Big Man rule, exercising untrammelled power, issuing orders and expecting them to be executed without dissent or delay. That has worked, so far, to limit the spread of COVID-19 in Sri Lanka. But will it work to tackle more complex and long-standing problems concerning the economy, interethnic relations, public administration and much else besides?

Countries become stable and prosperous by nurturing effective institutions and social trust over time, not with Big Man politics with its never-ending command-and-control, short-term, ad hoc fixes. That is something the Rajapaksas -- and all but a tiny minority of Sri Lankans -- don't seem to understand. Sri Lanka is now hurtling back to illiberal democracy. It may provide short-term political stability, but I doubt it will lead to better governance.

This Rajapaksa government, like the last one, espouses a collectivist economic ideology. Its first budget was full of tax cuts and expenditure entitlements, guaranteed to increase the fiscal deficit and public debt. The policy consists of diktats and constantly changing regulations on taxes, monetary expansion and import controls.

Sri Lanka was already in a debt trap when this government came to power. Total public debt is about 90% of gross domestic product, and total external debt, at over $50 billion, is about 60% of GDP. Then COVID-19 struck. The budget deficit may go up to 10% of GDP this year, and the economy may shrink by up to 5%. There is no fiscal space for tax cuts and extra public expenditure. The government desperately needs to negotiate debt moratoria, extra loans and possible debt restructuring with the International Monetary Fund and others. But, for now, it has no plan.

The Rajapaksas are unapologetic Sinhala-Buddhist nationalists. President Rajapaksa and the SLPP were elected with a huge majority of Sinhala votes but only a tiny percentage of ethnic-minority votes.

The Sinhala-Tamil cleavage is long-standing. The Easter Sunday blasts last year, perpetrated by Islamic radicals, opened a new cleavage between Sinhala Buddhists and Christians, on the one hand, and Muslims, on the other. The Rajapaksa Sinhala-Buddhist supremacist agenda is guaranteed to keep ethnic tensions on the boil. Muslims will be most at risk if that gets out of control.

President Rajapaksa has largely ignored the West, the IMF and other international organizations, but he is friendly with Narendra Modi, a fellow strongman and ethno-religious nationalist. China, however, remains "first friend." Money talks: Chinese state-backed investment is the only big game in town. There is a real possibility that Sri Lanka will rely on new Chinese loans to avert a macroeconomic crisis, especially if it does not come to a new agreement with the IMF.

Sri Lanka increasingly resembles a Chinese tributary state -- rather like a brief interlude in the fifteenth century, when Admiral Zheng He abducted a local king and took him to Beijing to pay obeisance to the emperor, after which an annual tribute was sent to China.

Sri Lanka is a bewitchingly beautiful country. Since ancient times, it has won the hearts of many a visitor. I would know since I grew up there -- I am half Sri Lankan, half British -- and have spent the past decade travelling all over the island to write a travel memoir.

But Sri Lanka is a little country with layer upon layer of complexity and paradox, and a dark side that has benighted its post-independence politics and institutions. As an adviser to the last government, I saw up close its shambolic disintegration. Understandably, Sri Lankans voted for the only realistic alternative: the Rajapaksas. The prospect of another decade of Rajapaksa hegemony does not fill me with optimism.

Prof. Razeen Sally is a visiting associate professor at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy at the National University of Singapore. He is also the author of "Return to Sri Lanka: Travels in a Paradoxical Island."